A common mistake of those against tobacco tax reforms is the application
of elementary math on the impact of reduced consumption on revenues.
That reduced tobacco consumption will generate revenue losses for the
government is a hasty conclusion and ignores the empirical fact that
demand for cigarettes is inelastic.
Inelasticity of cigarette demand is due to the highly addictive nature
of smoking. It simply means that tobacco consumption is not
proportionally responsive to changes in prices, i.e. a 10% price
increase will lead to a less than 10% decrease in consumption. To
illustrate more vividly, a P30 tax per pack will increase the price of
the most popular brand by 50%, from P40 to P60, ceteris paribus, while
consumption will be reduced by only 30-40%, with some (not all) smokers
quitting and some, just cutting down on the number of sticks they smoke.
Because cigarette demand is inelastic, we can increase taxes and achieve
both goals (though seemingly clashing) of raising additional revenues
and reducing cigarette consumption. Our current low level of cigarette
tax (44% of retail price vs. World Bank’s recommended 67-80%) gives us
ample room for raising taxes even up to more than P30 per pack without
incurring revenue losses.
Myth #2: Higher taxes will increase cigarette smuggling.
Related to the myth that increases in tobacco taxes will lead to revenue
losses is the unfounded claim that higher taxes will increase illicit
trade of cigarettes in the Philippines. More than price itself, other
factors, such as weak administration and poor enforcement of rules, are
largely responsible for the degree of smuggling in a country. Illicit
trade is mainly a function of corruption and institutional strength.
That the Philippines has the cheapest cigarettes in the world is a good
indicator that smuggling will not worsen with the implementation of tax
reforms. Add to that the anti-smuggling measures that the BIR (Bureau of
Internal Revenue) will be putting in place this year, the odds of a
worsening illicit market for cigarettes will be close to nil.
Myth #3: Tax reforms are anti-tobacco farmers.
In the past three hearings in Congress of the committee on ways and
means on excise tax bills, legislators mostly from the North were
hostile to the proposed reforms of the DoF (Department of Finance).
Their main argument: tobacco tax reforms will hurt the tobacco farmers.
What these legislators do not recognize is that tobacco farming in the
country has been on a downward trend for many years now. Over a span of
only 20 years, land devoted to cultivating tobacco has been halved.
Without much observed technological breakthroughs in tobacco farming, we
can easily deduce that many farmers have already shifted to alternative
crops or livelihoods.
The decline in tobacco farming is expected to continue, as more and more
people are becoming aware of the ill effects of smoking. What better
way to help the farmers than with tax reforms that will raise additional
funding to support their ongoing movement to livelihoods other than
tobacco farming?
The DoF proposes that 15% of the incremental revenues from cigarette
excise tax reforms (estimated at P75 billion for the next five years) be
dedicated for alternative livelihood programs for farmers in provinces
producing Burley and Native tobacco. On top of that, Virginia
tobacco-producing provinces will get an additional 15% of taxes on
locally manufactured Virginia-type cigarettes.
Moreover, with 98% of the local cigarettes market captured by a single
company, farmers are now facing a monopsonistic market for their
produce. The dominant single buyer of raw tobacco is driving down the
income of farmers. Avelino Dacanay, a farmer from the Ilocos Region,
observes that just before the merger of Philip Morris and Fortune
Tobacco in 2010, the price of raw tobacco was P97 per kilogram. In the
next crop season following the inception of Philip Morris Fortune
Tobacco Corp., the price dropped by 23% to P73 per kilogram.
The move to a unitary tax system will increase competition in the
tobacco industry. More players in the market will translate to more
buyers of raw tobacco, which will then improve the bargaining power of
farmers in setting prices.
In summary, tax reforms are pro-tobacco farmers. The reforms will help
farmers in their continuing movement to more lucrative income-generating
activities, expand livelihood opportunities for farmers, and give them
better prices for their produce.
Conclusion
It is comforting to know that the administration is grounded in truth,
as it is committed to pushing for genuine reforms in the excise tax
system. The departments of Health, Finance and Agriculture are already
in agreement that tax reforms will bring about net gains for the country
in terms of improved health of Filipinos, increased revenues for the
government, and broadened opportunities for farmers. I do hope that our
lawmakers will follow suit.
Walang komento:
Mag-post ng isang Komento